Proportional approval voting - Biblioteka.sk

Upozornenie: Prezeranie týchto stránok je určené len pre návštevníkov nad 18 rokov!
Zásady ochrany osobných údajov.
Používaním tohto webu súhlasíte s uchovávaním cookies, ktoré slúžia na poskytovanie služieb, nastavenie reklám a analýzu návštevnosti. OK, súhlasím


Panta Rhei Doprava Zadarmo
...
...


A | B | C | D | E | F | G | H | CH | I | J | K | L | M | N | O | P | Q | R | S | T | U | V | W | X | Y | Z | 0 | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 8 | 9

Proportional approval voting
 ...

Proportional approval voting (PAV) is a proportional electoral system for multiwinner elections. It is a multiwinner approval method that extends the highest averages method of apportionment commonly used to calculate apportionments for party-list proportional representation.[1] However, PAV allows voters to support only the candidates they approve of, rather than being forced to approve or reject all candidates on a given party list.[2]

In PAV, voters cast approval ballots marking all candidates they approve of; each voter's ballot is then treated as if all candidates on the ballot were on their own "party list." Seats are then apportioned between candidates in a way that ensures all coalitions are represented proportionally.

History

PAV is a special case of Thiele's voting rule, proposed by Thorvald N. Thiele.[3][4] It was used in combination with ranked voting in the Swedish elections from 1909 to 1921 for distributing seats within parties and in local elections.[4] PAV was rediscovered by Forest Simmons in 2001,[5] who gave it the name "proportional approval voting."

Method

Like its close cousin, satisfaction approval voting, PAV can be thought of as selecting a committee by testing all possible committees, then choosing the committee with the most votes. In satisfaction approval voting, each voter's ballot is split equally between all candidates they approve of, giving each one votes. If voters are perfectly strategic, and only support as many candidates as their party is entitled to, SAV creates a proportional result.

PAV makes one modification to remove this need for strategy: it only splits a voter's ballot after they have elected a candidate. As a result, voters can freely approve of losing candidates without diluting their ballot. Voters contribute a whole vote to the first candidate they support who is elected; half a vote to the second candidate; and so on.

Thus, if a ballot approves of candidates who are elected, that ballot contributes the -th harmonic number to that committee's vote total. In other words:[5][6]

The score for a given committee is calculated as the sum of the scores garnered from all the voters. We then choose the committee with the highest score.

Formally, assume we have a set of candidates , a set of voters , and a committee size . Let denote the set of candidates approved by voter . The PAV score of a committee with size is defined as . PAV selects the committee with the maximal score.

Example 1

Assume 2 seats to be filled, and there are four candidates: Andrea (A), Brad (B), Carter (C), and Delilah (D), and 30 voters. The ballots are:

  • 5 voters voted for A and B
  • 17 voters voted for A and C
  • 8 voters voted for D

There are 6 possible results: AB, AC, AD, BC, BD, and CD.

AB AC AD BC BD CD
score from the 5 voters voting for AB
score from the 17 voters voting for AC
score from the 8 voters voting for D